The Royal
Society for the Encouragement of Arts, Manufactures, and Commerce was an
important institution that helped transform Great Britain from a backwater in
1500 to the technological leader of the world by 1850. Recently, I spoke with
Anton Howes on Political Economy about the history of this organization and
what we can learn from this time period to encourage more innovation today.
Anton is the historian-in-residence at the Royal Society for the Encouragement of Arts, Manufactures, and Commerce. He is the author of the recently released authorized history “Arts and Minds: How the Royal Society of Arts Changed a Nation.”
Below is an abbreviated transcript of our conversation. You can read our full discussion here. You can also subscribe to my podcast on iTunes or Stitcher, or download the podcast on Ricochet.
Pethokoukis:
You have written that the British Isles in the 16th century were a backwater,
peripheral to European technological development. And yet, by the middle of the
19thcentury, the United Kingdom was
leading the entire world in technology. How
and when did that happen?
Howes:
That really is the question. It’s the first sustained economic growth that the
world had seen. The main reason it happens is that Brits in particular become
especially good at developing the kinds of institutions that spread innovation
further. What innovators managed to do in Britain, I think quite uniquely, was
consistently get victories in creating the sorts of institutions, laws, and
policies that would support innovation in general.
You
see this spread of an improving mentality from inventor to inventor. And at the
same time, there’s a sort of public spiritedness, in that they are not just
inventing for their own private gain (keeping secrets and so on), but also
actively trying to spread innovation further — spreading that mentality to
other people much as possible.
The other interesting thing is the
timing. By 1700, Britain seems to have this reputation for inventiveness and
improvement. And so I think we really need to look at the period before the
Industrial Revolution, or even 1660. We need to say, “Well, how is it that
the Royal Society could emerge in the first place?” I think the crucial century
that we really need to focus on is really 1550 to 1650. Clearly that’s when
something happens that’s quite special.
Can you connect the following dots, explaining how each led to the
next? I have Francis Bacon, then the
Royal Society of London for Improving Natural Knowledge, and then the subject
of your book: the Royal Society for the Encouragement of Arts, Manufactures and
Commerce.
Bacon systematizes a way of
thinking about the world. He’s a sort of lightning rod for the sorts of people
who are saying, “Let’s look at all of the existing knowledge that we
currently have and question everything, and we’ll rebuild what we currently
know from the ground up.”
And the Royal Society of London is
really set up by a bunch of people who essentially have been inspired by that
Baconian call. The Royal Society focused primarily on what we today would call
science; that is, discovery of new laws. By the 1750s, there’s this perceived need
for a specific institution that takes the extra step of applying this expanding
knowledge. And that’s where the Society of Arts fits in. Essentially, it’s
about application of knowledge.
What did the Royal Society for the
Encouragement of Arts, Manufactures and Commerce see as its mission at the
beginning? How did it go about that mission?
Anything
that could be for the public good was up for grabs — from tackling problems
that could have technological solutions to opening a new trade route.
They
tried to fill in the gaps of what wasn’t already being invented. For instance,
they very quickly decided that they wouldn’t accept patented inventions.
Patents in those days were extremely expensive and suggested that there was
already an incentive to invent that thing. So they focused on the sort of
things that wouldn’t otherwise be patented — what was less profitable, but
still useful. Safety improvements for workers, consumer safety improvements — things
that maybe couldn’t be covered by the patent system, but were still innovations, like signaling systems for
the Navy. They’d give a whole bunch of prizes for that sort of thing.
The
role of the Society sort of changed from kind of a prize-awarding organization
to being a place where reformers across society had a forum to promote those
reforms in a variety of sectors. And that evolution leads to the Great
Exhibition in 1851. How?
Instead
of using prizes all the time, they became more of a platform for the diffusion
of knowledge. Particularly when it came to combining existing specializations —
they started to see themselves as a platform for bridging specialties.
Since
about 1798, France held national exhibitions of industry where you could put in
one room all of the manufactures from throughout the country. Putting
everything physically in the same space allowed manufacturers to learn from one
another much more rapidly and also exposed consumers to what they didn’t already
know about — and didn’t know they wanted.
Eventually
this leads to the Great Exhibition of 1851, the pinnacle of British industrial
leadership in the world. Instead of just having these national exhibitions, they
have an international exhibition, which would also promote free trade. It seems
as though with every international exhibition, there was more and more
international cooperation and lowering of tariffs. You also get a lot of the
international standardization movements coming out of it. So these exhibitions became
these engines of international cooperation as well as of free trade.
What
advice would you give policymakers — whether in London or Washington — to
encourage a more innovative society?
I suggest doing the sort of thing that the French government did in the 1830s: purchasing patents and then releasing them to the public. Some work by Michael Kremer suggested a clever way of doing this: using auctions to discover the prices of those patents. Then the government could release the more valuable patents which are bottlenecks to technological progress, which is very common. For example, 3D printing has been around since the 1980s, but it’s only flourished as a sector since the mid-2000s because that’s when all the patents started to expire.
I’m not suggesting changing the patent system. That’s an extremely difficult thing to do. But you can supplement it by having this policy of patent buyouts.
The post 5 questions for Anton Howes on the Royal Society of Arts and British economic development | American Enterprise Institute appeared first on EPeak World News.
This article was first featured at https://epeak.in/2020/06/04/5-questions-for-anton-howes-on-the-royal-society-of-arts-and-british-economic-development-american-enterprise-institute/ on June 4, 2020 at 09:11AM by root
More Stories
Can this possibly be true? “Metal 3D printing is now possible on any 3D printer…with the right settings and a few minor upgrades like a hardened steel nozzle…” – July 2 2023 at 04:59PM
New NASA Funding Ignites 25 3D Printing Projects in Space Exploration – June 18 2023 at 04:34PM
Nvidia AI produces 3D models from 2D videos 3D printing applications forthcoming? – June 15 2023 at 02:55AM